Inclusive Growth

Global Housing Watch

Forecasting Forum

Energy & Climate Change

Okun’s law and digitalization in ASEAN-10 economies

From a paper by Martin Boďa, Mariana Považanová, and Katarína Vitálišová:

“Whilst the economic success of ASEAN countries is frequently attributed to the transformation of their economies towards digitalization and technical innovation, little is known about the unemployment-output behaviour of ASEAN economies in the course of the business cycle. One aspect of this conjunctural behaviour is studied in this chapter in the hope of providing insights into how the unemployment-output relationship–enacted in Okun’s law––unfolds in conjunction with the structural changes of their economies and other factors. A two-stage procedure is applied to that end. First, for a period of three decades, 1991–2022, a time-varying version of Okun’s law is estimated for each ASEAN economy. Second, the estimated Okun coefficients are matched against a set of explanatory variables including various metrics of digitalization, sectoral and labour market characteristics. The results indicate that in the majority of ASEAN economies unemployment was mostly insensitive to output, or that the unemployment-output relationship was constant and otherwise of a negligible magnitude, which corroborates the resilience of economic growth in the Southeast Asian region. Nonetheless, this sensitivity is heightened by the reorientation towards medium and high-tech industries whilst the adoption of digital technologies by the population has actually no effect per se.”

From a paper by Martin Boďa, Mariana Považanová, and Katarína Vitálišová:

“Whilst the economic success of ASEAN countries is frequently attributed to the transformation of their economies towards digitalization and technical innovation, little is known about the unemployment-output behaviour of ASEAN economies in the course of the business cycle. One aspect of this conjunctural behaviour is studied in this chapter in the hope of providing insights into how the unemployment-output relationship–enacted in Okun’s law––unfolds in conjunction with the structural changes of their economies and other factors.

Read the full article…

Posted by at 7:48 PM

Labels: Inclusive Growth

Monetary independence and liberalisation of capital flows: an unattainable duo inthe context of financial globalisation and eurozone accession?

From a paper by Klara Perica, Josip Visković, and Mario Pečarić:

“Financial openness affected the reduction and accumulation of reserves, the growth of the degree of monetary policy independence, while the choice of exchange rate regime was not statistically significant. The study thus confirms that monetary policy independence in the era of capital account liberalisation is limited regardless of the type of exchange rate regime.”

From a paper by Klara Perica, Josip Visković, and Mario Pečarić:

“Financial openness affected the reduction and accumulation of reserves, the growth of the degree of monetary policy independence, while the choice of exchange rate regime was not statistically significant. The study thus confirms that monetary policy independence in the era of capital account liberalisation is limited regardless of the type of exchange rate regime.”

Read the full article…

Posted by at 7:47 PM

Labels: Inclusive Growth

What can India do to industrialize?

This material first appeared on Noahpinion:

I really believe that Indian industrialization is one of the most important stories in the world today. The fate of over a billion people — most of them still pretty poor — hinges crucially on the question of whether the world’s most populous nation can lift itself out of poverty by its bootstraps, as China has done, and as Vietnam is now in the process of doing.

Instead of writing another post about Indian industrialization, I thought I’d solicit a guest post from Karan Bhasin, who knows a lot about the subject. Karan is a doctoral candidate at University at Albany, SUNY, whose research has documented India’s recent progress in reducing poverty. He’s joined in this post by Prakash Loungani, the Director of the M.S. in Applied Economics program at Johns Hopkins University, who teaches a course on economic growth with Karan. Together, they explain the next steps they think India needs to take in order to supercharge its industrial development.


In February 2023, Noah posed an important question: can India industrialize? The question has been on the minds of Indian economic policymakers since its independence in 1947. Recent attempts at industrializing include Modi Government’s “Make in India” program and the liberal use of industrial policy for sectors such as electronics, semiconductors among others. However, the emphasis on industrial development is not new—India’s second Five-Year Plan in 1956 had already identified rapid industrialization as a key strategy for poverty alleviation.

In the 1950s, India had its own version of the Western Solow growth model—this was the P.C. Mahalanobis growth model, which emphasized the role of investment in capital goods (heavy industry) to drive long-term economic growth. It argued that a country should prioritize investment in industries that produce capital goods (like machinery and equipment) to increase its capacity to produce all types of goods, including consumer goods, in the future. The capital allocation decisions undertaken by India on the basis of the Mahalanobis Model yielded a growth rate of 4.3 percent, encouragingly close to the government’s target of 4.5 percent for 1956-61. This contributed to a growing sense of confidence in the ‘planned approach’ as an effective way to achieve industrialization. The confidence was, however, short-lived as growth started to falter during the Third Five-Year Plan. Indian policymakers started to recognize the need for reforms in their approach, particularly as many East Asian economies had successfully transformed their economies and were rapidly industrializing. These economies had embraced international trade, liberal domestic economy and limited the state to important areas such as rule of law, education and healthcare services etc. To emulate at the success of these “Miracle Economies” – Indian economic policymakers embarked on similar reforms in 1991. The objective behind these reforms was to fundamentally reorient the Indian economy from a planned economy to a market economy, hoping at such reforms would help India rapidly industrialize and move to a higher growth path.

The 1991 reforms were successful in in many respects, but the success came with an Indian accent. Unlike East Asian peers, which first industrialized before pivoting towards services, India achieved success in export of high-value services even as it struggled with exports of labor-intensive products. Figure 1 illustrates that the share of manufacturing in India’s GDP has remained relatively flat, even as the services sector expanded significantly from 40% to 60% between 1980 and 2024. India is, therefore, paradoxically, a large labor-surplus economy which but struggles with labor-intensive production but instead specializes in production of high-value services (and also goods such as pharmaceuticals and more recently electronics).

Continue reading here.

This material first appeared on Noahpinion:

I really believe that Indian industrialization is one of the most important stories in the world today. The fate of over a billion people — most of them still pretty poor — hinges crucially on the question of whether the world’s most populous nation can lift itself out of poverty by its bootstraps, as China has done, and as Vietnam is now in the process of doing.

Read the full article…

Posted by at 11:28 AM

Labels: Inclusive Growth

Polycrisis, Neoliberalism and the State in the Twenty-First Century

From a paper by Maria Luísa Vasconcelos, Sandra Bernardo, Fátima Rocha:

“This article explores the relationship between polycrises, the weaknesses of neoliberal models, and
the evolving role of the State in managing uncertainty and promoting resilience. It argues that neoliberal policies, marked by deregulation and reduced State intervention, have deepened structural vulnerabilities, making societies more susceptible to systemic shocks. In response to interconnected crises, the State must be repositioned to play a more active role in market regulation, global coordination, and social protection. This shift calls for adaptive governance, and enhanced international cooperation, rather than a return to traditional interventionism. The study employs a qualitative methodology, using descriptive, explanatory, and interpretative approaches to analyse political dynamics in the twenty-first century.”

From a paper by Maria Luísa Vasconcelos, Sandra Bernardo, Fátima Rocha:

“This article explores the relationship between polycrises, the weaknesses of neoliberal models, and
the evolving role of the State in managing uncertainty and promoting resilience. It argues that neoliberal policies, marked by deregulation and reduced State intervention, have deepened structural vulnerabilities, making societies more susceptible to systemic shocks. In response to interconnected crises, the State must be repositioned to play a more active role in market regulation,

Read the full article…

Posted by at 7:58 AM

Labels: Inclusive Growth

Beneath the curves: central banking in the era of environmental labour market disruption

From a paper by Joseph Feyertag:

“Climate change, environmental degradation, and the accelerating transition to a low-carbon economy are reshaping global labour markets. These forces are altering both the demand for and supply of labour, with far-reaching implications for central banks. As institutions that closely monitor labour market dynamics to guide monetary policy, central banks will increasingly need to account for the disruptions caused by environmental pressures. Physical climate impacts and nature degradation are likely to reduce labour productivity and limit work capacity in vulnerable sectors — particularly in emerging markets and developing economies (EMDEs). At the same time, the growing need for climate mitigation and adaptation investments may tighten labour markets by increasing demand for skilled workers, while displacing those employed in pollution-intensive industries. This report addresses a critical gap in current analysis by exploring how environmental risks intersect with central banks’ mandates through the labour market. It aims to equip central banks with the insights needed to integrate these evolving risks into their policy frameworks and operational decisions.”

From a paper by Joseph Feyertag:

“Climate change, environmental degradation, and the accelerating transition to a low-carbon economy are reshaping global labour markets. These forces are altering both the demand for and supply of labour, with far-reaching implications for central banks. As institutions that closely monitor labour market dynamics to guide monetary policy, central banks will increasingly need to account for the disruptions caused by environmental pressures. Physical climate impacts and nature degradation are likely to reduce labour productivity and limit work capacity in vulnerable sectors — particularly in emerging markets and developing economies (EMDEs).

Read the full article…

Posted by at 7:56 AM

Labels: Energy & Climate Change

Home Older Posts

Subscribe to: Posts