Sunday, August 12, 2012
Olivier Coibion |
Loungani: Congratulations on your selection as an IMF Fellow. Is this your first stint at a policy institution?
Coibion: Thanks, I’m thrilled to be here! I worked for a year at the CEA [U.S. Council of Economic Advisers] in 2000-01. It gave me an enduring sense of how economic theory and empirical methods can help address policy questions and make a difference in people’s lives. And because I happened to be there during the transition from the Clinton to the Bush administration, it was fascinating to see the change in style and personalities—and in the dress code. The suits got much more sober and I even had to start wearing a tie once the Bush administration was in place.
Loungani: Dress is casual at the IMF over the summer. You see the suits out in full force in the fall. What will you work on during your year here?
Coibion: I’ll continue some of my work on inequality. One project will look at links between inequality and financial crises, which folks at the IMF have also studied. I’ve also been studying the impact of monetary policy on inequality—who gains, who loses when the Fed changes its policy. This gets debated in policy circles a lot but not much in academia. Ron Paul says that expansionary monetary policies, or debasing the currency as he always puts it, raises income inequality; people on the left like Jamie Galbraith say the opposite.
Loungani: What do you find?
Coibion: We find that expansionary monetary policy has typically reduced U.S. inequality in the short run. This suggests that when the central bank can’t cut interest rates any more—when rates hit the so-called ‘zero lower bound’, as is the case at present—inequality will be higher than it would be otherwise. To avoid these additional increases in inequality at a time of crisis, the government should use other tools, such as targeted fiscal policies. I hope to do some more work on this while I’m here. More generally, I’ll be studying how best to sequence fiscal and monetary policies when the multipliers—the impacts of the policies on the economy—associated with each may vary with the state of the economy.
Loungani: Do you think the Fed has done enough to promote recovery?
Coibion: I think the zero lower bound [on interest rates] has certainly limited the size of their response. They would be lowering rates further if they could. But as the IMF’s latest review of the U.S. economy noted, the Fed still has a few options to further support economic activity, given the weak state of labor markets and given the significant downside risks that still exist.
Loungani: Do you think that to avoid hitting the zero lower bound in the future, central banks should raise the target rate of inflation?
Coibion: No, I don’t. A higher inflation rate also has economic costs. So raising the target inflation rate will confer the benefit that we’ll be less likely to hit the zero lower bound. But such episodes are rare. So the high benefits conferred on rare occasions have to be balanced against the small but frequent costs of having higher inflation. In some work I’ve done, it turns out that the costs consistently outweigh the benefits for inflation rates above 2%. So rather than raise the target rate of inflation to deal with future episodes like the Great Recession, I’d prefer the more aggressive use of temporary policies designed for precisely this kind of episode, such as additional quantitative easing or fiscal policy.
Olivier Coibion–Recent Publications:
Olivier Coibion
Loungani: Congratulations on your selection as an IMF Fellow. Is this your first stint at a policy institution?
Coibion: Thanks, I’m thrilled to be here! I worked for a year at the CEA [U.S. Council of Economic Advisers] in 2000-01. It gave me an enduring sense of how economic theory and empirical methods can help address policy questions and make a difference in people’s lives. And because I happened to be there during the transition from the Clinton to the Bush administration,
Posted by 7:31 PM
atLabels: Profiles of Economists
Thursday, August 2, 2012
A new IMF report on US structural unemployment says that
while high long-term unemployment has not yet morphed into a permanent structural problem, it does pose an upward risk to the structural rate of unemployment. We have found that long-term unemployed are significantly less likely to find a job now than before the crisis, and that the loss in labor market matching efficiency observed since the recession is entirely due to a worsening of the labor matching of the long-term unemployed. Together, these results point to a risk that the structural rate of unemployment might be greater now than before the crisis.
Hence, forceful measures should be introduced that reduce long-term unemployment and address the risks associated with long spells of unemployment, namely skills erosion and a weaker attachment to the labor force. These measures include policies to increase demand for the long-term unemployed in the short run (active labor market policies, ALMP). When appropriately designed, such policies have been shown to be effective in improving employment and earnings prospects of long-term unemployed workers (Card et al, 2010; Card and Levine, 2000; Heinrich et al., 2008; Hotz et al., 2006). In particular, as discussed in the Staff report, a significant increase in ALMP resources is warranted given the persistently large pool of long-term unemployed and the risk that, as duration lengthens, their skills and attachment to the workforce might erode. Indeed, in terms of resources per long-term unemployed, the United States spends relatively little on active labor market policies, both compared to other OECD countries, and relative to its own pre-recession levels.
A new IMF report on US structural unemployment says that
while high long-term unemployment has not yet morphed into a permanent structural problem, it does pose an upward risk to the structural rate of unemployment. We have found that long-term unemployed are significantly less likely to find a job now than before the crisis, and that the loss in labor market matching efficiency observed since the recession is entirely due to a worsening of the labor matching of the long-term unemployed.
Posted by 3:34 PM
atLabels: Inclusive Growth
The authorities noted that the series of measures taken since last year to support the housing market were starting to bear fruit. These measures include in particular an expansion of the Home Affordable Refinancing Program (HARP) for loans owned or guaranteed by the GSEs, and a strengthening of the Home Affordable Modification Plan (HAMP), including loosened eligibility criteria through the elimination of debt service-to-income cutoffs, and the tripling of incentives for investors to carry out principal reductions under HAMP’s Principal Reduction Alternative (PRA) (Box 5). Recent data suggests that the October 2011expansion of HARP seems to have led to a significant increase in HARP refinancing. The share of loans that have benefited from a principal reduction under the modification program (Home Affordable Modification program of HAMP) has also been on the rise, and early signs show that the tripling of the incentives for principal reductions is receiving interest from investors, and is likely to spur further principal reductions in the future. The recent State Attorneys General Settlement with the major banks, which resolved claims about improper foreclosures and abuses in servicing the loans, could lead in the medium run to a non-trivial reduction in foreclosures, including through up to $34 billion of principal reduction. Early signs indicate that the settlement has led banks to delay foreclosures and also to increasingly substitute them with “short sales” of underwater properties, which are less costly and count toward the banks’ commitment for principal reduction under the settlement. The authorities highlighted that greater reliance on short sales, as opposed to foreclosures, could support the housing market going forward.
The mission welcomed this progress, but also noted that more aggressive policy action may be warranted to accelerate the resolution of the housing crisis. As noted in the Fed’s November 2011 white paper, housing markets do not self-correct efficiently and, absent forceful policies to support the market, prices could fall below their equilibrium levels due to feedback loops from prices to demand and supply. If house prices are anticipated to decline, potential buyers could stay out of the market even if interest rates are low. Moreover, a decline in prices reduces housing equity, triggering further defaults and foreclosures. Foreclosures, in turn, put renewed downward pressure on prices, not only by adding to the supply of houses for sale, but also because they lead to a destruction of value and impose “deadweight” losses on the economy, hurting consumer wealth and credit availability.
The IMF’s 2012 annual report on the US economy says that “house prices have shown some firming recently, with a surprising increase in Q1 2012.” It also highlights that
The authorities noted that the series of measures taken since last year to support the housing market were starting to bear fruit. These measures include in particular an expansion of the Home Affordable Refinancing Program (HARP) for loans owned or guaranteed by the GSEs, and a strengthening of the Home Affordable Modification Plan (HAMP),
Posted by 3:33 PM
atLabels: Global Housing Watch
Thursday, July 26, 2012
According to a new IMF working paper:
The large fiscal legacies of the global financial crisis have reignited the debate around the impact of fiscal policy onto economic activity during fiscal consolidations. The analysis in this paper shows that withdrawing fiscal stimuli too quickly in economies where output is already contracting can prolong their recessions without generating the expected fiscal saving. This is particularly true if the consolidation is centred around cuts to public expenditure—likely reflecting the fact that reductions in public spending have powerful effects on the consumption of financially-constrained agents in the economy—and if the size of the consolidation is large. Large consolidations make recessions more likely even when made at an expansion time. From a policy perspective this is especially relevant for periods of positive, though low growth. Accordingly, frontloading consolidations during a recession seems to aggravate the costs of fiscal adjustment in terms of output loss, while it seems to greatly delay the reduction in the debt-to-GDP ratio—which, in turn, can exacerbate market sentiment in a sovereign at times of low confidence, defying fiscal austerity efforts altogether. Again this is even truer in the case of consolidations based prominently on cuts to public spending.
Thus, a gradual fiscal adjustment, with a balanced composition of cuts to expenditure and tax increases boosts the chances that the consolidation will successfully (and rapidly) translate into lower debt-to-GDP ratios. Monetary policy can likely help alleviate further the pain of fiscal withdrawal if it is used proactively via reduction in the real interest rate.
According to a new IMF working paper:
The large fiscal legacies of the global financial crisis have reignited the debate around the impact of fiscal policy onto economic activity during fiscal consolidations. The analysis in this paper shows that withdrawing fiscal stimuli too quickly in economies where output is already contracting can prolong their recessions without generating the expected fiscal saving. This is particularly true if the consolidation is centred around cuts to public expenditure—likely reflecting the fact that reductions in public spending have powerful effects on the consumption of financially-constrained agents in the economy—and if the size of the consolidation is large.
Posted by 7:45 PM
atLabels: Inclusive Growth
Thursday, July 19, 2012
An already sluggish global recovery shows signs of further weakness, mainly because of continuing financial problems in Europe and slower-than-expected growth in emerging economies, the IMF said July 16 in a regular update to its World Economic Outlook.
An already sluggish global recovery shows signs of further weakness, mainly because of continuing financial problems in Europe and slower-than-expected growth in emerging economies, the IMF said July 16 in a regular update to its World Economic Outlook.
Posted by 2:05 PM
atLabels: Forecasting Forum
Subscribe to: Posts