Inclusive Growth

Global Housing Watch

Forecasting Forum

Energy & Climate Change

Tackling Unemployment: Return of the Two-Handed Approach

Unemployment in advanced economies averages 8% today, a sharp rise from 5 ½ % at the start of the Great Recession. European unemployment is particularly high—about 11% on average. What can be done?

In a celebrated mid-1980s paper, Olivier Blanchard, along with Rudi Dornbusch and others, argued that tackling the high unemployment and low growth in Europe at that time would require a ‘two-handed approach’: a combination of demand-side and supply-side policies. It is not coincidental that the IMF’s current advice to countries reflects the return of the two-handed approach.

In presentations delivered at the European Commission, ILO, World Bank and other venues, Prakash Loungani—advisor in the Research Department and co-chair of the IMF’s “Jobs & Growth” working group—has made the case for balancing demand and supply initiatives to tackle unemployment in advanced economies. He notes that, contrary to some assertions, unemployment and growth have remained linked during the Great Recession and the Not-So-Great Recovery. This preserves the hope that the jobs will return when the growth does.

Evidence suggests that the bulk of the rise in unemployment in most countries has been cyclical. Hence, as the Wall Street Journal noted recently, it’s time to “stop worrying about the ‘jobless recovery’ [and] start worrying about the recovery-less recovery.” Citing work on Okun’s Law by IMF authors and other recent evidence, the Journal concluded that “it isn’t unemployment benefits or other specific [structural] factors that are holding back hiring. It’s the economy, stupid.”

Several factors are behind the tepid recovery in output. In work done for the recent World Economic Outlook, Ayhan Kose, Prakash Loungani and Marco Terrones note that a key difference between the current global recovery and past global recoveries is that fiscal policy has not been able to provide the support this time that it did in the past—a point that has been picked by many observers including Paul Krugman (see the figure on fiscal spending below and Krugman’s essay here).

Real Primary Government Expenditures
Calibrating the pace of fiscal adjustment to growth conditions—and countering the effects of the adjustment through other policies if possible—to minimize the drag on demand is thus an essential part of the IMF’s advice to restore growth and lower unemployment. This is reflected for instance in the MD’s recent statement on Spain where she welcomed the government’s decision “to pursue a more gradual consolidation path” as a step to help the country in “securing a recovery and creating jobs.”

The two-handed approach does not neglect supply. In a recent Staff Discussion Note, Olivier Blanchard, Florence Jaumotte and Prakash Loungani discuss many labor market reforms that have been advocated in recent IMF programs in Europe. They argue that, by and large, these reforms can be expected to contribute to ‘micro flexibility’ (the ability of the economy to reallocate workers across jobs to boost productivity) and ‘macro flexibility’ (the ability of the economy to adjust to macroeconomic shocks).

Unemployment in advanced economies averages 8% today, a sharp rise from 5 ½ % at the start of the Great Recession. European unemployment is particularly high—about 11% on average. What can be done?

In a celebrated mid-1980s paper, Olivier Blanchard, along with Rudi Dornbusch and others, argued that tackling the high unemployment and low growth in Europe at that time would require a ‘two-handed approach’: a combination of demand-side and supply-side policies.

Read the full article…

Posted by at 1:39 PM

Labels: Inclusive Growth

House Prices in Switzerland

“House prices are high, but it’s too early to call it a bubble,” according to an IMF study on the Swiss Housing Market: What are the risks? It says that “real house prices are high, and at an all-time high for owner-occupied apartments. Prices have been on an increasing trend since the late 1990s and the average price for a single family home has increased by about 49 percent. Prices for owner occupied apartments have increased even more (72 percent) and in the last four years the annualized price increase (5 1/2 percent) substantially exceed nominal GDP growth. When deflating house prices by the CPI, owner-occupied apartment prices are slightly above the peak of the boom-bust period in the late 80s to early 90s. Single family home prices are still below the peak, but still high by historic standards. Residential house price increases are especially pronounced in certain segments and region. Turning to regional patterns, Geneva stands out with price increases far exceeding the other regions in both the single family home and the owner occupied segments. It is also important to note that the price increases started from already high price levels.” 

However, “current prices look less elevated when compared to income and rents. Following the
boom in the late 80s housing prices fell dramatically and their subsequent growth remained
subdued relative to growth in rents and in GDP per capita until the late 2000s, when housing price growth accelerated. While these ratios are still well below the levels reached at the peak of the previous boom, the ratio of price to rents for owner occupied apartments is already 15 percent above its long-term average.”

“House prices are high, but it’s too early to call it a bubble,” according to an IMF study on the Swiss Housing Market: What are the risks? It says that “real house prices are high, and at an all-time high for owner-occupied apartments. Prices have been on an increasing trend since the late 1990s and the average price for a single family home has increased by about 49 percent. Prices for owner occupied apartments have increased even more (72 percent) and in the last four years the annualized price increase (5 1/2 percent) substantially exceed nominal GDP growth.

Read the full article…

Posted by at 2:47 PM

Labels: Global Housing Watch

What’s Holding Back Hiring?

From the Wall Street Journal:

Stop worrying about the “jobless recovery.” Start worrying about the recovery-less recovery.

Nearly four years after the recession officially ended, the unemployment rate remains elevated, at 7.5%. The share of the population that’s working or looking for work is at a 30-year low. More than 2.5 million fewer Americans are working today than when the recession began.

Such grim statistics have led many economists to ask whether there might be deep, “structural” factors holding back hiring. Various papers have attributed the slow pace of job growth to the weak housing market, the downturn in specific industries and the long-run decline in the share of the population that’s working.

Others, however, have argued that there is little evidence for structural problems, and have said weak hiring is due to something much simpler: the slow pace of overall economic growth. In one recent paper, economists Laurence Ball, Daniel Leighand Prakash Loungani said the improvement in the job market during the recovery has been consistent with a long-documented relationship between unemployment and economic growth known as Okun’s Law.

In a new paper published by the National Bureau of Economic Research,University of Wisconsin economist (and blogger) Menzie Chinn and French economists Laurent Ferrara and Valerie Mignon also look at the relationship between economic growth and the job market. But rather than focus on unemployment, they focus on employment — an approach that allows them to avoid the nettlesome question of who should count as unemployed.

Mr. Chinn and his colleagues find that slow growth accounts for the majority of the continued jobs gap — but not all of it. The U.S. has about 1.2 million fewer jobs than it should based on long-run trends. The authors are careful not to say the entire gap is due to structural factors — some of it may be due to short-term issues, or to flaws in their economic model — but their findings do suggest the weak recovery alone doesn’t explain the weak job market.

Continue to the read the article here.

From the Wall Street Journal:

Stop worrying about the “jobless recovery.” Start worrying about the recovery-less recovery.

Nearly four years after the recession officially ended, the unemployment rate remains elevated, at 7.5%. The share of the population that’s working or looking for work is at a 30-year low. More than 2.5 million fewer Americans are working today than when the recession began.

Such grim statistics have led many economists to ask whether there might be deep,

Read the full article…

Posted by at 1:18 AM

Labels: Inclusive Growth

House Prices in Belgium

“Real estate prices have continued to increase steadily through the financial crisis, outpacing increases in other advanced countries,” according to the IMF’s annual economic report on Belgium. It says that “prices have increased by 60 percent in real terms since 2000, and—unlike in other EU countries—there has been no price correction during the crisis. Marked increases in price-to-income and price-to-rent ratios relative to historical average suggest significant overvaluation. However, these measures do not account for the fact that housing was relatively inexpensive to begin with, and that there is therefore a large catching up effect underlying the rise of these indicators. Also, the rental market is very narrow as it is focused only on low-income social housing on one hand and high-end apartments in Brussels on the other. A broader assessment, including a comparison of absolute price levels relative to the rest of Europe, suggests that the degree of overvaluation is of the order of 5 to 20 percent.”

“Real estate prices have continued to increase steadily through the financial crisis, outpacing increases in other advanced countries,” according to the IMF’s annual economic report on Belgium. It says that “prices have increased by 60 percent in real terms since 2000, and—unlike in other EU countries—there has been no price correction during the crisis. Marked increases in price-to-income and price-to-rent ratios relative to historical average suggest significant overvaluation. However, these measures do not account for the fact that housing was relatively inexpensive to begin with,

Read the full article…

Posted by at 3:55 PM

Labels: Global Housing Watch

Krugman on “How the Case for Austerity Has Crumbled”

An Excerpt from Krugman’s review in The New York Review of Books

“Neil Irwin’s The Alchemists gives us a time and a place at which the major advanced countries abruptly pivoted from stimulus to austerity. The time was early February 2010; the place, somewhat bizarrely, was the remote Canadian Arctic settlement of Iqaluit, where the Group of Seven finance ministers held one of their regularly scheduled summits. Sometimes (often) such summits are little more than ceremonial occasions, and there was plenty of ceremony at this one too, including raw seal meat served at the last dinner (the foreign visitors all declined). But this time something substantive happened. “In the isolation of the Canadian wilderness,” Irwin writes, “the leaders of the world economy collectively agreed that their great challenge had shifted. The economy seemed to be healing; it was time for them to turn their attention away from boosting growth. No more stimulus.””

“How decisive was the turn in policy? Figure 1 [see below. Also, read the graph’s corresponding article: The Great Divergence of Policies], which is taken from the IMF’s most recent World Economic Outlook, shows how real government spending behaved in this crisis compared with previous recessions; in the figure, year zero is the year before global recession (2007 in the current slump), and spending is compared with its level in that base year. What you see is that the widespread belief that we are experiencing runaway government spending is false—on the contrary, after a brief surge in 2009, government spending began falling in both Europe and the United States, and is now well below its normal trend. The turn to austerity was very real, and quite large.”

“On the face of it, this was a very strange turn for policy to take. Standard textbook economics says that slashing government spending reduces overall demand, which leads in turn to reduced output and employment. This may be a desirable thing if the economy is overheating and inflation is rising; alternatively, the adverse effects of reduced government spending can be offset. Central banks (the Fed, the European Central Bank, or their counterparts elsewhere) can cut interest rates, inducing more private spending. However, neither of these conditions applied in early 2010, or for that matter apply now. The major advanced economies were and are deeply depressed, with no hint of inflationary pressure. Meanwhile, short-term interest rates, which are more or less under the central bank’s control, are near zero, leaving little room for monetary policy to offset reduced government spending. So Economics 101 would seem to say that all the austerity we’ve seen is very premature, that it should wait until the economy is stronger.”
——

The Great Divergence of Policies article has also been featured in the Great Recession and Not-So-Great Recovery by the Financial Times, Free to Spend, Developing Economies Recover Quicker by the New York Times, The Non-Secret of Our Non-Success by The Conscience of a Liberal Blog, and How the IMF became the friend who wants us to work less and drink more by the Washington Post.

An Excerpt from Krugman’s review in The New York Review of Books

“Neil Irwin’s The Alchemists gives us a time and a place at which the major advanced countries abruptly pivoted from stimulus to austerity. The time was early February 2010; the place, somewhat bizarrely, was the remote Canadian Arctic settlement of Iqaluit, where the Group of Seven finance ministers held one of their regularly scheduled summits. Sometimes (often) such summits are little more than ceremonial occasions,

Read the full article…

Posted by at 7:57 PM

Labels: Forecasting Forum

Home Older Posts

Subscribe to: Posts